Hellermann v. Comm'r of Internal Revenue

Decision Date30 December 1981
Docket NumberDocket No. 7957-79.
Citation77 T.C. 1361
PartiesARTHUR K. HELLERMANN and V. LOUISE HELLERMANN, PETITIONERS v. COMMISSIONER of INTERNAL REVENUE, RESPONDENT
CourtU.S. Tax Court

OPINION TEXT STARTS HERE

Held: Gain which is attributable solely to inflation is income within the meaning of the 16th Amendment, and thus is taxable without apportionment. Accordingly, petitioners are liable for capital gains tax and the minimum tax under sec. 56, I.R.C. 1954, on the full dollar amount of gain realized from the sale in 1976 of real property purchased in 1964. Arthur K. Hellermann and V. Louise Hellermann, pro se.

Rogelio A. Villageliu, for the respondent.

OPINION

EKMAN , Judge:

Respondent determined a deficiency of $11,206.60 in petitioners' Federal income taxes for 1976. The sole issue for our decision is whether that portion of gain from the sale of property, which is attributable solely to inflation, is income within the meaning of the 16th Amendment.

All the facts have been stipulated and are so found. The stipulation of facts and exhibits attached thereto are incorporated herein by this reference. The pertinent facts are summarized below.

Petitioners Arthur K. Hellermann and V. Louise Hellermann resided in Milwaukee, Wis., when they filed their joint return for 1976. They resided in Hendersonville, Tenn., when they filed their petition and amended petition herein.

Petitioners purchased four buildings in 1964 for $93,312. They sold the buildings in 1976 for $264,000, and reported a capital gain of $170,688 on their 1976 return. They paid the appropriate capital gain taxes, but failed to compute or pay the additional minimum tax on items of tax preference as required by sections 55 to 58, I.R.C. 1954.

Respondent contends that petitioners are liable for the minimum tax because capital gain is an item of tax preference under section 57(a)(9)(A).1 Petitioners counter that they are not liable for the minimum tax and that they are entitled to a refund of capital gains tax paid in 1976.

Petitioners claim that much of their reported gain on the sale of the four buildings was due to inflation. They point out that the Consumer Price Index (CPI)2 had approximately doubled between 1964 and 1976.3 Thus, even though they received more dollars on the sale than they had paid to purchase the buildings, each 1976 dollar they received was worth less than each 1964 dollar they paid. From this they concluded that their economic gain on the sale was $88,167.4 However, they concede that they had a nominal gain of $170,688.

Petitioners assert that they should not be taxed on their nominal gain, but only on their economic gain. They argue that the portion of their nominal gain which is attributable solely to inflation does not constitute taxable income within the meaning of the 16th Amendment. Instead, they contend that, economically speaking, such gain is a return of capital. As they correctly observe, tax on a return of capital is a direct tax, subject to apportionment. 5 They maintain that to the extent the Internal Revenue Code permits that portion of nominal gain which is attributable to inflation to be taxed, it is an unconstitutional exercise of the Congress' power. They conclude that the Code must be interpreted in a manner which does not permit such gain to be taxed as income. As an appropriate means to that end, petitioners suggest that we adjust nominal gain to reflect the effects of inflation.

Respondent rejects as irrelevant petitioners' use of the CPI, or other measures of inflation, to calculate taxable income. He contends that nominal capital gain is taxable income whether or not such gain represents an increase in economic value. We agree with respondent, and therefore, need not decide whether the CPI is an appropriate measure with which to adjust taxable income. 6

We note at the outset that we have several times denied taxpayers deductions for losses due to inflation, on grounds that the tax law is not written to account for inflation.7 These cases do not control the decision in this case because they deal with deductions, not income. Deductions are a matter of legislative grace, and the Congress has absolute discretion to refrain from taxing what would otherwise be taxable income. New Colonial Ice Co. v. Helvering, 292 U.S. 435, 440 (1934). In contrast, Congress may not constitutionally tax as income, without apportionment, receipts which represent a return of capital. Southern Pacific Co. v. Lowe, 247 U.S. 330 (1918); Burnet v. Logan, 283 U.S. 404 (1931); Kerr v. Commissioner, 38 T.C. 723 (1962), affd. 326 F.2d 225 (9th Cir. 1964).

We reject petitioners' contention that nominal gain is not taxable income within the meaning of the 16th Amendment8 on two grounds. First, we rely on the well-established doctrine that Congress has the power and authority to establish the dollar as a unit of legal value with respect to the determination of taxable income, independent of any value the dollar might also have as a commodity. See Norman v. Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Co., 294 U.S. 240 (1935); Nortz v. United States, 294 U.S. 317 (1935); Perry v. United States, 294 U.S. 330 (1935); Legal Tender Cases, 79 U.S. (12 Wall.) 457 (1870). In the Legal Tender Cases, supra, the Supreme Court held that Congress had the power to declare treasury notes (“greenbacks”), which were backed by gold, to be legal tender. The Court held that paper money could be on a par with gold coins because both had the same legal value. Legal Tender Cases, supra at 530. The Court recognized that the statutory value of the nation's currency might not correspond to the market value of the bullion which backed the paper or from which the gold coins were made. It termed this discrepancy the difference between legal and intrinsic value. However, it did not doubt that Congress had the power to legislate such a difference. The Court viewed the Constitution as being “designed to provide the same currency, having a uniform legal value in all the States.* * * for this reason the power to coin money and regulate its value was conferred upon the Federal government,” and it reasoned that “Whatever power there is over the currency is vested in Congress.” Legal Tender Cases, supra at 545.

The cases reviewing the Gold Reserve Act of 1934, Norman v. Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Co., supra, Nortz v. United States, supra, and Perry v. United States, supra, further extended the power of Congress with respect to the currency. These cases challenged the Gold Reserve Act of 1934 9 as an unconstitutional impairment by Congress of the obligation of contract, both public and private. The Gold Reserve Act had effectively taken the United States off the domestic gold standard by removing gold coins from circulation as legal tender. This affected certain bonds containing so-called “gold clauses,” which were intended to protect the bondholder against devaluation of the currency by providing that the bonds would be paid off in gold of a particular weight and fineness. The Court held that these clauses were invalid insofar as they interfered with Congress' broad and comprehensive power to regulate the value of the currency and to create a unitary currency. Norman v. Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Co., supra at 316. The Court found that an expansive interpretation of the congressional power over revenue, finance, and currency was justified by:

the aggregate of the powers granted to the Congress, embracing the powers to lay and collect taxes, to borrow money, to regulate commerce with foreign nations and among the several States, to coin money, regulate the value thereof, and of foreign coin, and fix the standards of weights and measures, and the added express power “to make all laws which shall be necessary and proper for carrying into execution” the other enumerated powers. [ Norman v. Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Co., supra at 303, citing Juilliard v. Greenman, 110 U.S. 421, 439-440 (1884).]

Under this implicit constitutional authority, the Court concluded that Congress could choose “a uniform monetary system, and * * * reject a dual system, with respect to all obligations within the range of the exercise of its constitutional authority.” [Emphasis added.] Norman v. Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Co., supra at 316.

Petitioners concede that Congress has the power to require that the income tax be paid in dollars as legal tender, but argues that it does not have the power to measure gain in terms of dollars, because such dollars do not have a constant value. Given the reasoning behind the holding of the Legal Tender Cases, supra, and Norman v. Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Co., supra, we must disagree. Dollars have constant legal value under the uniform monetary system created by Congress.10 When petitioners sold the buildings in 1976, they realized a gain in legal value. The 16th Amendment does not prevent the Congress from taxing such gain as income if it chooses to do so.

As our second ground for rejecting petitioners' arguments, we rely upon the doctrine of common interpretation. As was stated by Judge Learned Hand, [the] meaning [of income] is * * * to be gathered from the implicit assumptions of its use in common speech.” United States v. Oregon-Washington R. & Nav. Co., 251 F. 211, 212 (2d Cir. 1918). Thus, the meaning of income is not to be construed as an economist might, but as a layperson might. Petitioners received many more dollars for the buildings than they had paid for them. The extra...

To continue reading

Request your trial
18 cases
  • Nat'l-Standard Co. v. Comm'r of Internal Revenue
    • United States
    • U.S. Tax Court
    • March 21, 1983
    ...in Kenan the obligation was at all times a dollar obligation, the value of which remained constant for tax purposes. See Hellerman v. Commissioner, 77 T.C. 1361 (1981). In such a situation, the amount of the gain or loss is clearly the difference between the dollar amount of the obligation ......
  • Rowlee v. Comm'r of Internal Revenue
    • United States
    • U.S. Tax Court
    • June 15, 1983
    ...contain any argument with respect to that evidence. 6. Another useful discussion of the question of ‘gain‘ appears in Hellermann v. Commissioner, 77 T.C. 1361 (1981). In that case, the Court held that gain attributable solely to inflation, though nominal, was income within the meaning of th......
  • Peninsula Steel Prods. v. Comm'r of Internal Revenue
    • United States
    • U.S. Tax Court
    • June 17, 1982
    ...thus eliminating from earnings any artificial profits resulting from inflationary increases in inventory costs.” Cf. Hellermann v. Commissioner, 77 T.C. 1361 (1981). Before the years in issue, petitioner and Monotech consistently valued inventories using the lower of cost or market, identif......
  • Newman v. Commissioner
    • United States
    • U.S. Tax Court
    • August 6, 1984
    ...81-1 USTC ¶ 9382, 646 F. 2d 1185 (CA7 1981), affg. a Memorandum Opinion of this Court9 Dec. 36,088(M); Hellermann v. Commissioner Dec. 38,527, 77 T.C. 1361 (1981). See also generally McCoy v. Commissioner 83-1 USTC ¶ 9152, 696 F. 2d 1234 (CA9 1983), affg. Dec. 37,967 76 T.C. 1027 We hold fo......
  • Request a trial to view additional results

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT