Standard Oil Co of California and Standard Stations v. United States

Decision Date13 June 1949
Docket NumberNo. 279,279
Citation93 L.Ed. 1371,69 S.Ct. 1051,337 U.S. 293
PartiesSTANDARD OIL CO. OF CALIFORNIA AND STANDARD STATIONS, Inc. v. UNITED STATES
CourtU.S. Supreme Court

As Amended On Denial of Rehearing Oct. 10, 1949.

Appeal from the United States District Court for the Southern District of California.

Mr. John M. Hall, Los Angeles, Cal., for appellants.

Mr. Herbert A. Bergson, Washington, D.C., for appellee.

Mr. Justice FRANKFURTER delivered the opinion of the Court.

This is an appeal to review a decree enjoining the Standard Oil Company of California and its wholly-owned subsidiary, Standard Stations, Inc.,1 from enforcing or entering exclusive supply contracts with any independent dealer in petroleum products and automobile accessories. The use of such contracts was successfully assailed by the United States as violative of § 1 of the Sherman Act2 and § 3 of the Clayton Act.3 The Standard Oil Company of California, a Delaware corporation, owns petroleum-producing resources and refining plants in California and sells petroleum products in what has been termed in these proceedings the 'Western area'—Arizona, California, Idaho, Nevada, Oregon, Utah and Washington. It sells through its own service stations, to the operators of independent service stations, and to industrial users. It is the largest seller of gasoline in the area. In 1946 its combined sales amounted to 23% of the total taxable gallonage sold there in that year: sales by company-owned service stations constituted 6.8% of the total, sales under exclusive dealing contracts with independent service stations, 6.7% of the total; the remainder were sales to industrial users. Retail service-station sales by Standard's six leading competitors absorbed 42.5% of the total taxable gallonage; the remaining retail sales were divided between more than seventy small companies. It is undisputed that Standard's major competitors employ similar exclusive dealing arrangements. In 1948 only 1.6% of retail outlets were what is known as 'split-pump' stations, that is, sold the gasoline of more than one supplier.

Exclusive supply contracts with Standard had been entered, as of March 12, 1947, by the operators of 5,937 independent stations, or 16% of the retail gasoline outlets in the Western area, which purchased from Standard in 1947 $57,646,233 worth of gasoline and $8,200,089.21 worth of other products. Some outlets are covered by more than one contract so that in all about 8,000 exclusive supply contracts are here in issue. These are of several types, but a feature common to each is the dealer's undertaking to purchase from Standard all his requirements of one or more products. Two types, covering 2,777 outlets, bind the dealer to purchase of Standard all his requirements of gasoline and other petroleum product as well as tires, tubes, and batteries. The remaining written agreements, 4,368 in number, bind the dealer to purchase of Standard all his requirements of petroleum products only. It was also found that independent dealers had entered 742 oral contracts by which they agreed to sell only Standard's gasoline. In some instances dealers who contracted to purchase from Standard all their requirements of tires, tubes, and batteries, had also orally agreed to purchase of Standard their requirements of other automobile accessories. Of the written agreements, 2,712 were for varying specified terms; the rest were effective from year to year but terminable 'at the end of the first 6 months of any contract year, or at the end of any such year, by giving to the other at least 30 days prior thereto written notice. * * *' Before 1934 Standard's sales of petroleum products through independent service stations were made pursuant to agency agreements, but in that year Standard adopted the first of its several requirements-purchase contract forms, and by 1938 requirements contracts had wholly superseded the agency method of distribution.

Between 1936 and 1946 Standard's sales of gasoline through independent dealers remained at a practically constant proportion of the area's total sales; its sales of lubricating oil declined slightly during that period from 6.2% to 5% of the total. Its proportionate sales of tires and batteries for 1946 were slightly higher than they were in 1936, though somewhat lower than for some intervening years; they have never, as to either of these products, exceeded 2% of the total sales in the Western area.

Since § 3 of the Clayton Act was directed to prohibiting specific practices even though not covered by the broad terms of the Sherman Act,4 it is appropriate to consider first whether the enjoined contracts fall within the prohibition of the narrower Act. The relevant provisions of § 3 are:

'It shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in the course of such commerce, to lease or make a sale or contract for sale of goods, wares, merchandise, machinery, supplies, or other commodities, whether patented or unpatented, for use, consumption, or resale within the United States * * * on the condition, agreement, or understanding that the lessee or purchaser thereof shall not use or deal in the goods * * * of a competitor or competitors of the * * * seller, where the effect of such lease, sale, or contract for sale or such condition, agreement, or understanding may be to substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line of commerce.'

Obviously the contracts here at issue would be proscribed if § 3 stopped short of the qualifying clause beginning, 'where the effect of such lease, sale, or contract for sale * * *.' If effect is to be given that clause, however, it is by no means obvious, in view of Standard's minority share of the 'line of commerce' involved, of the fact that that share has not recently increased, and of the claims of these contracts to economic utility, that the effect of the contracts may be to lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly. It is the qualifying clause, therefore, which must be construed.

The District Court held that the requirement of showing an actual or potential lessening of competition or a tend ncy to establish monopoly was adequately met by proof that the contracts covered 'a substantial number of outlets and a substantial amount of products, whether considered comparatively or not.' Given such quantitative substantiality, the substantial lessening of competition—so the court reasoned—is an automatic result, for the very existence of such contracts denies dealers opportunity to deal in the products of competing suppliers and excludes suppliers from access to the outlets controlled by those dealers. Having adopted this standard of proof, the court excluded as immaterial testimony bearing on 'the commercial merits or demerits of the present system as contrasted with a system which prevailed prior to its establishment and which would prevail if the court declared the present arrangement (invalid).' The court likewise deemed it unnecessary to make findings, on the basis of evidence that was admitted, whether the number of Standard's competitors had increased or decreased since the inauguration of the requirements-contract system, whether the number of their dealers had increased or decreased, and as to other matters which would have shed light on the comparative status of Standard and its competitors before and after the adoption of that system. The court concluded:

'Grant that, on a comparative basis, and in relation to the entire trade in these products in the area the restraint is not integral. Admit also that control of distribution results in lessening of costs and that its abandonment might increase costs. * * * Concede further, that the arrangement was entered into in good faith, with the honest belief that control of distribution and consequent concentration of representation were economically beneficial to the industry and to the public, that they have continued for over fifteen years openly, notoriously and unmolested by the Government, and have been practised by other major oil companies competing with Standard, that the number of Standard outlets so controlled may have decreased, and the quantity of products supplied to them may have declined, on a comparative basis. Nevertheless, as I read the latest cases of the Supreme Court, I am compelled to find the practices here involved to be violative of both statutes. For they affect injuriously a sizeable part of interstate commerce, or,—to use the current phrase—'an appreciable segment' of interstate commerce.'

The issue before us, therefore, is whether the requirement of showing that the effect of the agreements 'may be to substantially lessen competition' may be met simply by proof that a substantial portion of commerce is affected or whether it must also be demonstrated that competitive activity has actually diminished or probably will diminish.5 Since the Clayton Act became effective, this Court has passed on the applicability of § 3 in eight cases, in five of which it upheld determinations that the challenged agreement was violative of that Section. Three of these—United Shoe Machinery Corp. v. United States, 258 U.S. 451, 42 S.Ct. 363, 66 L.Ed. 708; International Business Machines Corp. v. United States, 298 U.S. 131, 56 S.Ct. 701, 80 L.Ed. 1085; International Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.S. 392, 68 S.Ct. 12, 92 L.Ed. 20—involved contracts tying to the use of a patented article all purchases of an unpatented product used in connection with the patented article. The other two casesStandard Fashion Co. v. Magrane-Houston Co., 258 U.S. 346, 42 S.Ct. 360, 66 L.Ed. 653; Fashion Originators' Guild v. Federal Trade Comm'n, 312 U.S. 457, 61 S.Ct. 703, 85 L.Ed. 949—involved requirements contracts not unlike those here in issue.

The Standard Fashion case, the first of the five holding that the Act had been violated, settled one question of interpretation of § 3. The Court said:

'Section 3...

To continue reading

Request your trial
390 cases
  • Ixchel Pharma, LLC v. Biogen, Inc.
    • United States
    • United States State Supreme Court (California)
    • 3 Agosto 2020
    ...what capital expenditures are justified — offer the possibility of a predictable market." ( Standard Oil Co. of California v. United States (1949) 337 U.S. 293, 306–307, 69 S.Ct. 1051, 93 L.Ed. 1371 ; see also Sterling Merchandising, Inc. v. Nestle, S.A. (1st Cir. 2011) 656 F.3d 112, 123 ["......
  • Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Qualcomm Inc.
    • United States
    • U.S. District Court — Northern District of California
    • 21 Mayo 2019
    ...expense and risk of storage in the quantity necessary for a commodity having a fluctuating demand." Std. Oil Co. v. United States , 337 U.S. 293, 306, 69 S.Ct. 1051, 93 L.Ed. 1371 (1949).The exclusive dealing arena is one where § 1 and § 2 of the Sherman Act diverge to some degree, at least......
  • Classen v. Weller
    • United States
    • California Court of Appeals
    • 19 Julio 1983
    ...In fact, "[t]ying agreements serve hardly any purpose beyond the suppression of competition." (Standard Oil Co. v. United States (1949) 337 U.S. 293, 305-306, 69 S.Ct. 1051, 1058, 93 L.Ed. 1371.) The greater the market control over the tying product (here the limited number of Tobin-Clark l......
  • Meijer, Inc. v. Barr Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
    • United States
    • U.S. District Court — District of Columbia
    • 11 Agosto 2008
    ...by Ill. Tool Works, Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28, 126 S.Ct. 1281, 164 L.Ed.2d 26 (2006); Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 306, 69 S.Ct. 1051, 93 L.Ed. 1371 (1949) (finding that exclusive supply contracts "may assure supply, afford protection against rises in price, ......
  • Request a trial to view additional results
3 firm's commentaries
  • Corporate And Financial Weekly Digest - December 14, 2012
    • United States
    • Mondaq United States
    • 18 Diciembre 2012
    ...remarked that "[t]ying agreements serve hardly any purpose beyond the suppression of competition," see Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 US 293, 305 (1949), seemingly embracing a per se rule against all tying, it has since rejected that logic and the majority of tying arrangements are ......
  • De Facto Exclusive Dealing: What A Difference A Day Makes
    • United States
    • Mondaq United States
    • 24 Diciembre 2013
    ...the origin of modern exclusive dealing analysis is the Standard Station case of 1949, Standard Oil Co. of California v. United States, 337 U.S. 293 (1949). The issue to be determined, of course, is whether the conduct at issue substantially forecloses competitive opportunities in a given pr......
  • Antitrust Exclusive Dealing Claims Given 'Short-Shrift' In Dismissal. How Long Is Short? An Analysis In Search Of Context
    • United States
    • Mondaq United States
    • 22 Agosto 2013
    ...the likelihood of competitive foreclosure sufficient to raise antitrust concerns. For example, in Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293 (1949) ("Standard Stations") the Supreme Court devised what has become known as the "quantitative substantiality" test. This test measured whethe......
75 books & journal articles
  • Table of Cases
    • United States
    • ABA Antitrust Library Antitrust Handbook for Franchise and Distribution Practitioners
    • 1 Enero 2008
    ...506 U.S. 447 (1993), 26 Table of Cases 209 Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911), 4 Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293 (1949), 116, 122 Standfacts Credit Servs. v. Experian Info. Solutions, Inc., 405 F. Supp. 2d 1141 (C.D. Cal. 2005), 81 State Oil Co. v. Khan, 52......
  • Tying meets the new institutional economics: farewell to the chimera of forcing.
    • United States
    • University of Pennsylvania Law Review Vol. 146 No. 1, November 1997
    • 1 Noviembre 1997
    ...of the `tied' product would convince freely choosing buyers to select it over others, anyway."); Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 306 (1949) ("If the manufacturer's brand of the tied product is in fact superior to that of competitors, the buyer will presumably choose it anyw......
  • United States Law and the Proposed Code of Conduct on the Transfer of Technology
    • United States
    • Antitrust Bulletin No. 23-4, December 1978
    • 1 Diciembre 1978
    ...for a substitute would be so detailedthatthey couldnot practicably be supplied. See, e.g., Standard Oil v. UnitedStates, 337 U.S. 293(1949);Kolene Corp. v, Motor City MetalTreating,Inc., 307 F. Supp. 1251, 1269-70(E.D.Mich.1969),atf'd, 440 F.2d 77 (6th Cir.), cert. denied, 404 U.S. CODEOFCO......
  • Table of cases
    • United States
    • ABA Antitrust Library Market Power Handbook. Competition Law and Economic Foundations. Second Edition
    • 6 Diciembre 2012
    ...Airlines, 431 F.3d 917 (6th Cir. 2005), 9, 83 Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911), 13 Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293 (1949), 74 State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3 (1997), 14 Sullivan v. NFL, 34 F.3d 1091 (1st Cir. 1994), 13 T Tampa Elec. Co. v. Nashville Coa......
  • Request a trial to view additional results

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT