Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. Linkline Commc'ns, Inc.

Decision Date25 February 2009
Docket NumberNo. 07–512.,07–512.
Citation77 USLW 4130,172 L.Ed.2d 836,129 S.Ct. 1109,555 U.S. 438
PartiesPACIFIC BELL TELEPHONE CO., dba AT & T CALIFORNIA, et al. v. LINKLINE COMMUNICATIONS, INC., et al.
CourtU.S. Supreme Court

OPINION TEXT STARTS HERE

Syllabus*

Petitioners (hereinafter AT & T) own infrastructure and facilities needed to provide “DSL” service, a method of connecting to the Internet at high speeds over telephone lines. As a condition for a recent merger, the Federal Communications Commission requires AT & T to provide wholesale DSL transport service to independent firms at a price no greater than the retail price of AT & T's DSL service. The plaintiffs in this case, respondents here, are independent Internet service providers that compete with AT & T in the retail DSL market in California. The plaintiffs do not own all the facilities needed to supply DSL service, and must lease wholesale DSL transport service from AT & T. They filed suit under § 2 of the Sherman Act, asserting that AT & T unlawfully “squeezed” their profit margins by setting a high price for the wholesale DSL transport service it sells and a low price for its own retail DSL service. This maneuver allegedly placed the plaintiffs at a competitive disadvantage, allowing AT & T to maintain monopoly power in the DSL market. AT & T moved for judgment on the pleadings, arguing that the plaintiffs' claims were foreclosed by Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 410, 124 S.Ct. 872, 157 L.Ed.2d 823, in which this Court held that a firm with no antitrust duty to deal with its rivals has no obligation to provide those rivals with a “sufficient” level of service. The District Court found that AT & T had no antitrust duty to deal with the plaintiffs, but nonetheless denied the motion, holding that Trinko did not address price-squeeze claims. The court certified its order for interlocutory appeal on the question whether Trinko bars price-squeeze claims when the parties are required to deal by federal communications law, but not antitrust law. The Ninth Circuit affirmed, holding that Trinko did not address the viability of price-squeeze claims, and thus the plaintiffs' complaint stated a potentially valid § 2 claim.

Held:

1. The case is not moot. The plaintiffs now agree that their claims must meet the Brooke Group test for predatory pricing, apparently apart from their price-squeeze theory. That test established two requirements for predatory pricing: below-cost retail pricing and a ‘dangerousprobability’ that the defendant will recoup any lost profits, see Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 222–224, 113 S.Ct. 2578, 125 L.Ed.2d 168. Despite the plaintiffs' new position, the parties continue to seek different relief: AT & T seeks reversal of the decision below and dismissal of the complaint, while the plaintiffs seek leave to amend their complaint to allege a Brooke Group claim. It is also not clear that the plaintiffs have unequivocally abandoned their price-squeeze claims. Prudential concerns favor answering the question presented; absent a decision on the merits, the Circuit conflict that this Court granted certiorari to resolve would persist. P. 1117.

2. A price-squeeze claim may not be brought under § 2 when the defendant has no antitrust duty to deal with the plaintiff at wholesale. Pp. 1118 – 1124.

(a) Businesses are generally free to choose the parties with whom they will deal, as well as the prices, terms, and conditions of that dealing. See United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300, 307, 39 S.Ct. 465, 63 L.Ed. 992. But in rare circumstances, a dominant firm may incur antitrust liability for purely unilateral conduct, such as charging “predatory” prices. Brooke Group,supra, at 222–224, 113 S.Ct. 2578. There are also limited circumstances in which a firm's unilateral refusal to deal with its rivals can give rise to antitrust liability. See Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 608–611, 105 S.Ct. 2847, 86 L.Ed.2d 467. Here, plaintiffs do not allege predatory pricing, and the District Court concluded that there was no antitrust duty to deal. Plaintiffs challenge a different type of unilateral conduct in which a firm “squeezes” its competitors' profit margins. This requires the defendant to operate in both the wholesale (“upstream”) and retail (“downstream”) markets. By raising the wholesale price of inputs while cutting its own retail prices, the defendant can raise competitors' costs while putting downward pressure on their revenues. Price-squeeze plaintiffs assert that defendants must leave them a “fair” or “adequate” margin between wholesale and retail prices. Pp. 1118 – 1119.

(b) Where there is no duty to deal at the wholesale level and no predatory pricing at the retail level, a firm is not required to price both of these services in a manner that preserves its rivals' profit margins. Pp. 1119 – 1121.

(i) Any challenge to AT & T's wholesale prices is foreclosed by a straightforward application of Trinko. The claim in Trinko addressed the quality of Verizon's support services, while the claims in this case challenge AT & T's pricing structure. But for antitrust purposes, there is no meaningful distinction between price and nonprice components of a transaction. The nub of the complaint in both cases is identical—the plaintiffs alleged that the defendants (upstream monopolists) abused their power in the wholesale market to prevent rival firms from competingeffectively in the retail market. But a firm with no antitrust duty to deal in the wholesale market has no obligation to deal under terms and conditions favorable to its competitors. See Trinko, supra, at 410, 124 S.Ct. 872. Had AT & T simply stopped providing DSL transport service to the plaintiffs, it would not have run afoul of the Sherman Act. Thus, it was not required to offer this service at the wholesale prices the plaintiffs would have preferred. P. 1119.

(ii) The other component of a price-squeeze claim is the assertion that the defendant's retail prices are “too low.” Here too plaintiffs' claims find no support in existing antitrust doctrine. [C]utting prices in order to increase business often is the very essence of competition.” Matsushita Elec. Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 594, 106 S.Ct. 1348, 89 L.Ed.2d 538. To avoid chilling aggressive price competition, the Court has carefully limited the circumstances under which plaintiffs can state a Sherman Act claim by alleging that the defendant's prices are too low. See Brooke Group, supra, at 222–224, 113 S.Ct. 2578. The complaint at issue here has no allegation that AT & T's conduct met either Brooke Group requirement. Recognizing a price-squeeze claim where the defendant's retail price remains above cost would invite the precise harm the Court sought to avoid in Brooke Group : Firms might raise retail prices or refrain from aggressive price competition to avoid potential antitrust liability. See 509 U.S., at 223, 113 S.Ct. 2578. Pp. 1120 – 1121.

(c) Institutional concerns also counsel against recognizing such claims. This Court has repeatedly emphasized the importance of clear rules in antitrust law. Recognizing price-squeeze claims would require courts simultaneously to police both the wholesale and retail prices to ensure that rival firms are not being squeezed. Courts would be aiming at a moving target, since it is the interaction between these two prices that may result in a squeeze. Moreover, firms seeking to avoid price-squeeze liability will have no safe harbor for their pricing practices. The most commonly articulated standard for price squeezes is that the defendant must leave its rivals a “fair” or “adequate” margin between wholesale and retail prices; this test is nearly impossible for courts to apply without conducting complex proceedings like rate-setting agencies. Some amici argue that a price squeeze should be presumed if the defendant's wholesale price exceeds its retail price. But if both the wholesale price and the retail price are independently lawful, there is no basis for imposing antitrust liability simply because a vertically integrated firm's wholesale price is greater than or equal to its retail price. Pp. 1121 – 1122.

(d) The District Court on remand should consider whether an amended complaint filed by the plaintiffs states a claim upon which relief may be granted under the pleading standard articulated in Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 561–563, 127 S.Ct. 1955, 167 L.Ed.2d 929; whether plaintiffs should be given leave to amend their complaint to bring a Brooke Group claim; and such other matters properly before it. Pp. 1122 – 1123.

503 F.3d 876, reversed and remanded.

ROBERTS, C. J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., joined. BREYER, J., filed an opinion concurring in the judgment, in which STEVENS, SOUTER, and GINSBURG, JJ., joined.

Ed Kolto, Gleam O. Davis, Los Angeles, CA, Patrick J. Pascarella, San Antonio, Texas, Michael K. Kellogg, Aaron M. Panner, Kellogg, Huber, Hansen, Todd, Evans & Figel, P.L.L.C., Washington, D.C., for Petitioners.

Maxwell M. Blecher, Gary M. Joye, Blecher & Collins, P.C., Los Angeles, CA, for Respondents.

Chief Justice ROBERTS delivered the opinion of the Court.

The plaintiffs in this case, respondents here, allege that a competitor subjected them to a “price squeeze” in violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act. They assert that such a claim can arise when a vertically integrated firm sells inputs at wholesale and also sells finished goods or services at retail. If that firm has power in the wholesale market, it can simultaneously raise the wholesale price of inputs and cut the retail price of the finished good. This will have the effect of “squeezing” the profit margins of any competitors in the retail market. Those firms will have to pay more for the inputs the...

To continue reading

Request your trial
3 books & journal articles
  • Antitrust Restoration from California Anchored by a New Monopolization Synthesis
    • United States
    • California Lawyers Association Competition: Antitrust, UCL and Privacy (CLA) No. 33-1, March 2023
    • Invalid date
    ...Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585 (1985); Eastman Kodak, supra note 72; Trinko, supra note 26; Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc'ns, Inc., 555 U.S. 438 (2009).79. See, e.g., Viamedia, Inc. v. Comcast Corp., 951 F.3d 429, 454-59 (7th Cir. 2020); Four Corners Nephrology, supra note 61, at 1224-25......
  • Platforms, Power, and the Antitrust Challenge: a Modest Proposal to Narrow the U.s.-europe Divide
    • United States
    • University of Nebraska - Lincoln Nebraska Law Review No. 98, 2021
    • Invalid date
    ...8. 10. See Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, 540 U.S. 398 (2004); Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. Linkline Commc'ns, Inc., 555 U.S. 438 (2009); Eleanor Fox, The Efficiency Paradox , in HOW THE CHICAGO SCHOOL OVERSHOT THE MARK: THE EFFECT OF CONSERVATIVE ECONOMIC ANALYSIS ON U.......
  • Restoring Balance in the Test for Exclusionary Conduct
    • United States
    • California Lawyers Association Competition: Antitrust, UCL and Privacy (CLA) No. 24-1, March 2015
    • Invalid date
    ...Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966); see also Einer Elhauge, Defining Better Monopolization Standards, 56 Stanford L. Rev. 253 (2003).8. 555 U.S. 438 (2009).9. 540 U.S. 398 (2004).10. United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001), cert. denied, 534 U.S. 952 (2001).11. 342 U.......

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT