John Doe 1 v. Abbott Laboratories

Decision Date07 July 2009
Docket NumberNo. 08-17699.,08-17699.
Citation571 F.3d 930
PartiesJOHN DOE 1 and John Doe 2, on behalf of themselves and all other persons similarly situated, Plaintiffs-Appellees, v. ABBOTT LABORATORIES, Defendant-Appellant. Service Employees International Union Health and Welfare Fund, on behalf of themselves and all other persons similarly situated, Plaintiffs-Appellees, v. Abbott Laboratories, Defendant-Appellant.
CourtU.S. Court of Appeals — Ninth Circuit

James F. Hurst, Winston & Strawn LLP, Chicago, IL, (argued); Jeffrey I. Weinberger, Munger, Tolles & Olson LLP, Los Angeles, CA, for the defendant-appellant.

Richard R. Wiebe, Law Office of Richard R. Wiebe, San Francisco, CA, (argued); Christopher T. Heffelfinger, Bermand DeValerio, San Francisco, CA, for plaintiffs-appellees John Doe 1, John Doe 2, and Individual Class Members.

Michael W. Stocker, Labaton Sucharow LLP, New York, NY, for plaintiffs-appellees Service Employees International Union Health and Welfare Fund and for the Certified Class.

Appeal from the United States District Court for the Northern District of California, Claudia Wilken, District Judge, Presiding. D.C. Nos. 4:04-cv-01511-CW; 4:04-cv-4203-CW.

Before: MARY M. SCHROEDER, STEPHEN REINHARDT and PAMELA ANN RYMER, Circuit Judges.

RYMER, Circuit Judge:

Do allegations of monopoly leveraging through pricing conduct in two markets state a claim under § 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2, absent an antitrust refusal to deal (or some other exclusionary practice) in the monopoly market or below-cost pricing in the second market? Following Pacific Bell Telephone Co. v. Linkline Communications, Inc., ___ U.S. ___, 129 S.Ct. 1109, 172 L.Ed.2d 836 (2009), we hold that no such claim may be brought. As the district court held to the contrary, we reverse.1

I

John Does 1 and 2 and the Service Employees International Union Health and Welfare Fund (collectively, "Does") represent certified classes of HIV patients and their medical plans who purchase Norvir, a drug made by Abbott Laboratories that "boosts" the effectiveness of protease inhibitors used to fight the disease. According to Does, Norvir gives Abbott a monopoly in the booster market. Norvir was originally sold as a standalone protease inhibitor, but it turned out to be more useful as a booster taken in low dosages along with other inhibitors. Abbott also sells a "boosted" protease inhibitor, Kaletra, which consists of Abbott's protease inhibitor compound lopinavir combined in a single pill with a boosting dose of ritonavir (the generic name for Norvir).

Meanwhile, Abbott competitors such as Bristol Meyers-Squibb (whose protease inhibitor is marketed as Reyataz) and GlaxoSmithKline (whose inhibitor is marketed as Lexiva), were given permission by the FDA to promote Norvir as a booster to be taken along with their own inhibitors. Once this happened, Abbott increased the price of Norvir from $1.71 to $8.57 per 100 mg, but did not increase the price of Kaletra. The effect, Does say, was to raise the total cost to the patient of boosted protease inhibitor therapies provided by Abbott's competitors (that is, when a patient uses Norvir along with a competitor's inhibitor such as Reyataz or Lexiva). In this way, Abbott allegedly leveraged its Norvir monopoly to attempt to monopolize the boosted market for Kaletra.

Abbott moved for dismissal and for summary judgment on the grounds that no § 2 claim was stated, that Does failed to show antitrust injury, and that Abbott lacked monopoly power in the boosted protease inhibitor market. The district court disagreed in a series of rulings. See In re Abbott Labs. Norvir Anti-Trust Litig., 562 F.Supp.2d 1080 (N.D.Cal.2008); 442 F.Supp.2d 800 (N.D.Cal.2006); Serv. Employees Int'l Union Health & Welfare Fund v. Abbott Labs., No. 04-4203-CW, 2005 WL 528323 (N.D.Cal. Mar. 2, 2005) (order denying Abbott's motion to dismiss); Doe v. Abbott Labs., No. 04-1511-CW, 2004 WL 3639688 (N.D.Cal. Oct. 21, 2004) (same).

The parties then entered into a settlement agreement. Assuming approval by the district court, the agreement provides that Abbott will pay $10 million into a settlement fund and take an interlocutory appeal on condition that, if the case ends up being dismissed, Abbott will pay no more but if Does prevail, it will pay up to an additional $17.5 million depending on the degree of success. The district court approved both the settlement and interlocutory appeal, certifying three issues: (1) whether antitrust injury has been shown; (2) whether Abbott has monopoly power in the boosted protease inhibitor market; and (3) whether the below-cost pricing test for bundled discounts that we adopted in Cascade Health Solutions v. PeaceHealth, 515 F.3d 883 (9th Cir.2008), applies to this monopoly leveraging case. Abbott timely appealed.2

II

The settlement arrangement in this case implicates Gator.com Corp. v. L.L. Bean, Inc., 398 F.3d 1125, 1128-32 (9th Cir.2005) (en banc), thus our jurisdiction, so we address this issue first. In Gator, the parties to an action for declaratory judgment reached a settlement that ended the controversy on the merits and left open only a side issue of personal jurisdiction. In those circumstances we believed the appeal was moot. Unlike Gator, however, we are persuaded that the merits are still at issue here. Accordingly, we have jurisdiction to proceed. See Nixon v. Fitzgerald, 457 U.S. 731, 743-44, 102 S.Ct. 2690, 73 L.Ed.2d 349 (1982); Havens Realty Corp. v. Coleman, 455 U.S. 363, 371, 102 S.Ct. 1114, 71 L.Ed.2d 214 (1982).

As the district court's rulings were on a motion to dismiss and for summary judgment, our review is de novo. E. & J. Gallo Winery v. EnCana Corp., 503 F.3d 1027, 1033 (9th Cir.2007); Camacho v. Bridgeport Fin. Inc., 430 F.3d 1078, 1079 (9th Cir.2005).

III

Time, and the United States Supreme Court, have overtaken this case. The district court concluded that Does' claims for monopolization and attempted monopolization3 of the market for boosted protease inhibitors could go forward on a theory of monopoly leveraging as articulated in Image Technical Services, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195, 1202 (9th Cir.1997), and were not foreclosed by Cascade. In Image Technical, the defendant refused to sell aftermarket parts over which it had monopoly power to independent service organizations with whom it competed in the market for aftermarket services. We described the plaintiff's theory as "monopoly leveraging" and upheld a verdict in its favor. In Cascade, the defendant sold a bundle or package of goods for a lower price than it charged for the goods purchased individually. We held that the exclusionary element of § 2 cannot be satisfied by reference to bundled discounts unless the discounts result in prices below an appropriate measure of the seller's costs. Cascade, 515 F.3d at 900-03 (citing Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., Inc., 549 U.S. 312, 319-20, 325-26, 127 S.Ct. 1069, 166 L.Ed.2d 911 (2007); Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 222-24, 113 S.Ct. 2578, 125 L.Ed.2d 168 (1993)). However, since then, the Supreme Court rendered a decision in Linkline, a price-squeezing case, that controls the outcome here.

In Linkline, independent internet service providers that competed with AT & T in the retail DSL market, and also leased DSL transport service from AT & T at the wholesale level, argued that AT & T subjected them to a price squeeze in violation of § 2. 129 S.Ct. at 1114-15. AT & T was a vertically integrated firm that sold inputs at wholesale and finished goods or services at retail. Id. at 1115. As such, it was a player in the DSL market at both the wholesale and retail levels, providing plaintiffs with transport service and selling DSL service to consumers at retail. Id. The plaintiffs contended that their profit margins were unfairly squeezed by AT & T's practice of setting high prices in the wholesale transport market while keeping retail prices for its own DSL service low. Id. at 1118-19. The Court held that plaintiffs could not state a claim under § 2 when the defendant was under no antitrust duty to sell the inputs to its rivals.

In doing so, the Court reiterated the basic rule that mere possession of monopoly power and the practice of charging monopoly prices does not run afoul of § 2. Id. at 1118; see Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407, 124 S.Ct. 872, 157 L.Ed.2d 823 (2004) (Trinko). "Simply possessing monopoly power and charging monopoly prices does not violate § 2; rather, the statute targets `the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.'" Linkline, 129 S.Ct. at 1118 (quoting United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71, 86 S.Ct. 1698, 16 L.Ed.2d 778 (1966)). And when predatory pricing is at issue, a plaintiff must demonstrate that "(1) `the prices complained of are below an appropriate measure of its rival's costs'; and (2) there is a `dangerous probability' that the defendant will be able to recoup its `investment' in below-cost prices." Id. at 1120 (quoting Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 222-24, 113 S.Ct. 2578).

The Court analyzed each market separately. At the input or wholesale level, it found Trinko controlling even though Trinko involved the provision of "insufficient assistance" whereas Linkline involved a price-squeeze. Id. at 1119. In Trinko, a customer of one of Verizon's competitors claimed that Verizon had denied competitors access to interconnection support services which impaired their ability to deliver, hence the customer's ability to obtain, local telephone service in the downstream market. Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407, 124 S.Ct. 872. This presented no § 2 problem for, as explained in Linkline, "if a firm has no antitrust duty to deal with its competitors at...

To continue reading

Request your trial
80 cases
  • Hensley v. San Diego Gas & Elec. Co.
    • United States
    • California Court of Appeals Court of Appeals
    • January 31, 2017
    ...financial stake in the resolution of the question presented in this Court" and was not moot under Havens Realty ]; Doe v. Abbott Labs. (9th Cir. 2009) 571 F.3d 930, 932–933 [merits were still at issue despite contingent settlement providing for payment depending on outcome of appeal]; compa......
  • Safeway Inc. v. Laboratories
    • United States
    • U.S. District Court — Northern District of California
    • January 14, 2011
    ...to John Doe 1 v. Abbott Laboratories, No. C 04–1511 CW. Although that case also concerned the December, 2003 increase in Norvir's price, the Doe plaintiffs based their Section 2 claim on a theory of monopoly leveraging. See John Doe 1 v. Abbott Laboratories, 571 F.3d 930, 933 (9th Cir.2009)......
  • CHURCH v. MAYER LABORATORIES INC.
    • United States
    • U.S. District Court — Northern District of California
    • April 1, 2011
    ...Act.8 Mot. at 13. Relying on Pacific Bell Telephone Co. v. Linkline Commc'ns., Inc., 129 S. Ct. 1109 (2009) and Doe v. Abbott Labs., 571 F.3d 930, 935 (9th Cir. 2009), C&D argues that "when an essential part of an antitrust claim involves cutting prices (whether a rebate, discount, or strai......
  • Aerotec Int'l, Inc. v. Honeywell Int'l, Inc.
    • United States
    • U.S. Court of Appeals — Ninth Circuit
    • September 9, 2016
    ...cognizable harm to competition when the wholesale price and the retail price are independently lawful.” Doe 1 v. Abbott Labs. , 571 F.3d 930, 934–35 (9th Cir. 2009). Such is the case here.III. Robinson-Patman Act—Price Discrimination Aerotec alleges that Honeywell engages in secondary-line ......
  • Request a trial to view additional results
11 books & journal articles
  • Table of Cases
    • United States
    • ABA Antitrust Library Pharmaceutical Industry Antitrust Handbook. Second Edition
    • December 8, 2018
    ...2010), 162 Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984), 157, 381, 382 John Doe 1 and John Doe 2 v. Abbot Labs., 571 F.3d 930 (9th Cir. 2009), 376, 381 Johnson & Johnson/Pfizer, No. C-4180 (FTC 2007), 205, 206 K Kaiser Found. Health Plan v. Abbott Labs., 552 F.3d 1033......
  • Table of Cases
    • United States
    • ABA Antitrust Library Market Definition in Antitrust. Theory and Case Studies
    • December 6, 2012
    ...OF CASES Abbott Labs. Norvir Antitrust Litig., In re, 442 F. Supp. 2d 800 (N.D. Cal. 2006), rev’d sub nom. Doe v. Abbott Labs., 571 F.3d 930 (9th Cir. 2009), 327, 328 Abraham v. Intermountain Health Care, 461 F.3d 1249 (10th Cir. 2006), 302, 304 Ad/Sat v. Associated Press, 181 F.3d 216 (2d ......
  • Section 2 of The Sherman Act
    • United States
    • ABA Antitrust Library Model Jury Instructions in Civil Antitrust Cases
    • December 8, 2016
    ...n.4. Since Trinko , courts have increasingly rejected monopoly leveraging as a viable antitrust theory. See, e.g. , Doe 1 v. Abbott Labs., 571 F.3d 930, 935 (9th Cir. 2009); Schor v. Abbott Labs., 457 F.3d 608, 611-12 (7th Cir. 2006); Covad Commc’ns Co. v. Bell Atl. Corp., 398 F.3d 666, 672......
  • Specfic Forms of Monopolizing Conduct
    • United States
    • ABA Antitrust Library Monopolization and Dominance Handbook
    • January 1, 2021
    ...amended complaint properly alleged predatory pricing. linkLine , 555 U.S. at 456–57. 59. Id . at 452. In John Doe I v. Abbott Labs. , 571 F.3d 930 (9th Cir. 2009), the Ninth Circuit held that linkLine bars a claim against the monopolist of one of two complementary products, who charges a mo......
  • Request a trial to view additional results

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT