Valspar Corp. v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co., 16-1345.
Decision Date | 14 September 2017 |
Docket Number | No. 16-1345.,16-1345. |
Citation | 873 F.3d 185 |
Parties | VALSPAR CORPORATION; Valspar Sourcing, Inc., Appellant v. E.I. DU PONT DE NEMOURS AND COMPANY |
Court | U.S. Court of Appeals — Third Circuit |
James M. Lockhart [Argued], James P. McCarthy, Kathryn E. Wendt, Lindquist & Vennum, 80 South 8th Street, 2000 IDS Center, Minneapolis, MN 55402, Frederick L. Cottrell, III, Jason J. Rawnsley, Chad M. Shandler, Richards Layton & Finger, 920 North King Street, One Rodney Square, Wilmington, DE 19801, Counsel for Plaintiffs-Appellants
Randa Adra, Crowell & Moring, 590 Madison Avenue, 20th Floor, New York, NY 10022, Clifton S. Elgarten, Shari R. Lahlou [Argued], Benjamin C. Wastler, Crowell & Moring, 1001 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W., Washington, DC 20004 Kathleen F. McDonough, John A. Sensing, Potter Anderson & Corroon, 1313 North Market Street, Wilmington, DE 19801, Counsel for Defendant-Appellee
Richard M. Brunell, American Antitrust Institute, Suite 1100, 1730 Rhode Island Avenue, N.W., Washington, DC 20036, Counsel for American Antitrust Institute as Amicus Curiae in support of Plaintiff-Appellant
Before: HARDIMAN and KRAUSE, Circuit Judges, and STENGEL,* Chief District Judge.
This appeal involves an alleged conspiracy to fix prices in the titanium dioxide industry in violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act. Appellant Valspar, a purchaser of titanium dioxide, claimed Appellee DuPont conspired with other titanium dioxide suppliers to fix prices. Valspar argued that the price-fixing agreement was made manifest primarily by thirty-one parallel price increase announcements issued by the suppliers. DuPont countered that the parallel pricing was not the product of an agreement, but rather the natural consequence of the marketplace. Specifically, DuPont posited that because the market for titanium dioxide is an oligopoly, the price movement was caused by "conscious parallelism"—an economic theory that explains oligopolists will naturally follow a competitor's price increase in the hopes that each firm's profits will increase. The District Court agreed with DuPont and granted its motion for summary judgment. We will affirm.
The facts of this case were essentially undisputed in the District Court. The parties agree that the market for titanium dioxide is an oligopoly. Titanium dioxide is a commodity-like product with no substitutes, the market is dominated by a handful of firms, and there are substantial barriers to entry.
Valspar, a large-scale purchaser of titanium dioxide, alleges that a group of titanium dioxide suppliers conspired to increase prices. It claims that the conspiracy began when DuPont—the largest American supplier—joined the Titanium Dioxide Manufacturers Association (TDMA) in 2002, when the association opened participation to non-European companies. Shortly after joining the TDMA, DuPont announced a price increase. Within two weeks, DuPont's price increase was matched by Millennium, Kronos, and Huntsman (other TDMA members and members of the alleged conspiracy). This began what Valspar alleged to be the "Conspiracy Period"—twelve years during which the alleged conspirators announced price increases 31 times.
Valspar claims the conspiracy ended in late 2013 when DuPont exited the TDMA. According to Valspar's calculations, the conspirators inflated the cost of titanium dioxide by an average of 16%. Because Valspar purchased $1.27 billion of titanium dioxide from DuPont during the relevant period, it claims it was overcharged to the tune of $176 million.
In 2010, a class of titanium dioxide purchasers filed a price-fixing action against the suppliers in the United States District Court for the District of Maryland. Valspar opted out of that class and the remaining defendant suppliers settled the case after they were denied summary judgment. See In re Titanium Dioxide Antitrust Litig. , 959 F.Supp.2d 799, 832 (D. Md. 2013). Valspar then filed its own claim in the United States District Court for the District of Minnesota, which was subsequently severed. Valspar settled all claims except this one against DuPont, which was transferred to the United States District Court for the District of Delaware, where DuPont moved for summary judgment. Although presented with "substantially the same record ... as in the Maryland Class Action," the District Court reached a "different conclusion." Valspar Corp. v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours , 152 F.Supp.3d 234, 252 (D. Del. 2016). Reviewing the record and our Court's precedents, the District Court found that "evidence of an actual agreement to fix prices" was "lacking." Id. at 253. Reasoning that such evidence is necessary for a plaintiff to survive summary judgment, the District Court granted DuPont's motion. Id.
The District Court had jurisdiction under 28 U.S.C. § 1331. We have appellate jurisdiction under 28 U.S.C. § 1291. Our standard of review is intertwined with substantive antitrust law and the parties dispute its contours. We therefore begin by reviewing the applicable law.
Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits "[e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade." 15 U.S.C. § 1. Unlike § 2 of the Sherman Act, which addresses monopolization and other illegal unilateral conduct, § 1 applies only when there is an agreement to restrain trade; so a single firm's independent action, no matter how anticompetitive its aim, does not implicate § 1. Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Serv. Corp. , 465 U.S. 752, 761, 104 S.Ct. 1464, 79 L.Ed.2d 775 (1984). While some offenses under § 1 are reviewed for reasonableness, Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc. , 551 U.S. 877, 885–86, 127 S.Ct. 2705, 168 L.Ed.2d 623 (2007), others have no possible competitive virtue and are therefore per se illegal, Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc. , 441 U.S. 1, 19–20, 99 S.Ct. 1551 (1979). Horizontal price fixing (i.e ., price fixing among competitors) is one such per se violation because it is a "threat to the central nervous system of the economy." United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co. , 310 U.S. 150, 224 n.59, 60 S.Ct. 811, 84 L.Ed. 1129 (1940).
Oligopolies pose a special problem under § 1 because rational, independent actions taken by oligopolists can be nearly indistinguishable from horizontal price fixing. This problem is the result of "interdependence," which occurs because "any rational decision [in an oligopoly] must take into account the anticipated reaction of the other firms." In re Flat Glass Antitrust Litig ., 385 F.3d 350, 359 (3d Cir. 2004) (alteration omitted) (quoting Philip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law 207 (2d ed. 2000)). In a market with many firms, "the effects of any single firm's price and output decisions ‘would be so diffused among its numerous competitors that they would not be aware of any change.’ " Id . (quoting Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra , at 206). The opposite is true in an oligopoly, where any price movement "will have a noticeable impact on the market and on its rivals." Id. (quoting Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra , at 206); see also In re Text Messaging Antitrust Litig. , 782 F.3d 867, 875 (7th Cir. 2015) ( ).
This "oligopolistic rationality" can cause supracompetitive prices because it discourages price reductions while encouraging price increases. A firm is unlikely to lower its price in an effort to win market share because its competitors will quickly learn of that reduction and match it, causing the first mover's profits to decline and a subsequent decline in the overall profits of the industry. Flat Glass , 385 F.3d at 359. Similarly, if a firm announces a price increase, other market participants will know that Id. (quoting Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra , at 207–08).
The Supreme Court has explained that this behavior does not violate antitrust laws. See Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp. , 509 U.S. 209, 227, 113 S.Ct. 2578, 125 L.Ed.2d 168 (1993). Even though such interdependence or "conscious parallelism" harms consumers just as a monopoly does, it is beyond the reach of antitrust laws for two reasons. First, some courts and scholars theorize "that interdependent behavior is not an ‘agreement’ within the term's meaning under the Sherman Act." Flat Glass , 385 F.3d at 360 ). And second, "it is close to impossible to devise a judicially enforceable remedy for ‘interdependent’ pricing."
Clamp-All Corp. v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Inst. , 851 F.2d 478, 484 (1st Cir. 1988) (Breyer, J.). The problem is this: "How does one order a firm to set its prices without regard to the likely reactions of its competitors?" Id.
"When faced with whether a plaintiff has offered sufficient proof of an agreement to preclude summary judgment, a court must generally apply the same summary judgment standards that apply in other contexts." Flat Glass , 385 F.3d at 357. Accordingly, a court will enter summary judgment when the evidence shows "no genuine dispute as to any material fact and the movant is entitled to judgment as a matter of law." Fed. R. Civ. P. 56(a). As in other summary judgment contexts, we "review the record as a whole and in the light most favorable to the nonmovant, drawing reasonable inferences in its favor." In re Chocolate Confectionary Antitrust Litig. , 801 F.3d 383, 396 (3d Cir. 2015).
However, we have recognized there is "an important distinction"...
To continue reading
Request your trial-
In re Dealer Mgmt. Sys. Antitrust Litig.
...a jury." [1030] at 11. Citing Valspar Corp. v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co. , 152 F. Supp. 3d 234, 244 (D. Del. 2016), aff'd , 873 F.3d 185, 201 (3d Cir. 2017), Defendants claim that "Courts have rejected Dr. Williams's liability opinions in cases where he relied on similarly conclusory st......
-
Jones v. Micron Tech. Inc.
...an oligopoly must anticipate, or, at the very least consider, the reactions of the other competitors. Valspar Corp. v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours and Co. , 873 F.3d 185, 191 (3d Cir. 2017). In fact, seemingly anomalous price hikes in oligopolistic markets are often the result of non-conspirato......
-
Premier Comp Solutions LLC v. UPMC
...Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp. , 475 U.S. at 594, 106 S.Ct. 1348 ; See also Valspar Corp. v. E. I. Du Pont de Nemours & Co. , 873 F.3d 185, 192 (3d Cir. 2017).Notwithstanding, when the moving party has carried its burden under Rule 56(c), its opponent must do more than si......
-
IPIC-Gold Class Entm't, LLC v. AMC Entm't Holdings, Inc., 01-17-00805-CV
...a right to deal, or refuse to deal, with whomever it likes, as long as it does so independently."); Valspar Corp. v. E.I. Du Pont de Nemours & Co. , 873 F.3d 185, 190–91 (3d Cir. 2017) (Sherman Act prohibition on restraint of trade does not implicate "a single firm's independent action, no ......
-
Direct Evidence of a Sherman act Agreement
...something more—allegation or evidence—that raises a plausible inference of agreement. 15 Valspar Corp. v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours and Co., 873 F.3d 185, 191 (3d Cir. 2017) (internal citations and quotations omitted). 16 Id. at 191–92 (quoting Clamp-All Corp. v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Inst., 85......
-
Pleading, Discovery, and Proof of Sherman act Agreements: Harmonizing Twombly and Matsushita
...Litig., 959 F. Supp. 2d 799 (D. Md. 2013). 166 Valspar Corp. v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours, 152 F. Supp. 3d 234, 252 (D. Del. 2016), aff’d , 873 F.3d 185 (3d Cir. 2017). 167 Haley Paint , 804 F. Supp. 2d at 421. 168 Id. at 422–23. 169 Id. at 422. 170 Id. at 425. 171 Id. at 425. 172 Id. at 426.......
-
DISAPPROVAL OF QUICK-LOOK APPROVAL: ANTITRUST AFTER NCAA v. ALSTON.
...(235.) Id. at 122. (236.) See supra note 209 and accompanying text. (237.) See. e.g., Valspar Corp. v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co., 873 F.3d 185, 201 (3d Cir. 2017); Seagood Trading Corp. v. Jerrico, Inc., 924 F.2d 1555, 1574 (11th Cir. 1991) ("[W]hen the defendant puts forth a plausi......
-
Reflections on Matsushita and 'Equilibrating Tendencies': Lessons for Competition Authorities
...is effectively highlighted by the contrast between the majority and minority opinions in Valspar Corp. v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co. , 873 F.3d 185 (3d Cir. 2017), with the latter arguing for reading Matsushita in context and the former applying it broadly. 171 Agreement Containing Conse......